An updated Aug 2007 version of this appeared here. The 2007 article also appeared in AToL on August 24, 2007 .
PKT
mailing
list archive
To: pkt@xxxxxxxxxxxxxxxx
Subject: Re: Liquidity
From: Basil Moore <bjm@xxxxxxxxxxxxxxxx>
Date: Sun, 17 Jun 2001 12:43:47 -0400
Henry
I found your discussion of liquidity very informative and useful. Thank you for informing us.
But I have a problem with your theoretical model. As William keeps reminding you, it is simply wrong to regard the supply of credit money as either given, or exogenously determined. Credit money as you more than most know is bank deposits. As bank liabilities, deposits are simply the record of bank assets, primarily bank loans. "LOANS CAUSE DEPOSITS".
So you cannot talk about the quantity theory (QT) in the usual (Friedman) sense, which explicitly assumes that the supply of money is exogenously under the control of the CB. If money is endogenous, the QT is simply an identity, and must not be read as money "causing" anything, since money is itself caused by other variables in the system, in this case primarily business demand for working capital.
I would like to encourage you to try to retell your story of liquidity with explicit recognition that the supply of credit money is determined by the demand for bank credit. Then we can make inroads in the liquidity problem.
Basil Moore
At 05:35 PM 6/14/01 -0400, you [Henry
C. K. Liu] wrote:
Economists refer frequently to liquidity in the abstract. Yet in reality, liquidity is difficult to define and even more difficult to measure. On Wall Street, liquidity refers to the ability to buy or sell an asset quickly and in large volume without substantially affecting the asset's price. Shares in large blue-chip stocks like General Electric, used to be considered liquid, a description long since rendered invalid because of volatility. Of the several dimensions of market liquidity, two of the most important are tightness and depth. Tightness is a market's ability to match supply and demand at low cost (measured by bid-ask spreads), while market depth relates to the ability of a market to absorb large trade flows without a significant impact on prices (approximated by volumes, quote sizes, on-the-run/off-the-run spreads and volatilities). When market participants raise concerns about the decline in market liquidity, they typically refer to a reduced ability to deal without having prices move against them, that is, about reduced market depth.
According to current market commentary, liquidity in many markets never fully recovered from the sharp deterioration experienced during the 1998 financial crisis. However, influential market participants nevertheless continue to express the view that liquidity conditions were, at the current juncture, not a cause of acute concern. Moreover, it is acknowledged that cycles in liquidity crises have been a recurring feature of financial markets.
Commonly used indicators of market liquidity, notoriously imperfect as measures of liquidity conditions, also suggest a rather benign picture. While the autumn of 1998 is indeed identified as an adverse shock to the liquidity of financial markets, liquidity indicators seem to suggest that, with the notable exception of the US government bond market, liquidity conditions have been broadly restored to pre-crisis levels. However, the usual indicators typically capture only a single dimension of market liquidity and none of them is forward looking in nature, making it difficult to draw any conclusions as to what liquidity conditions might be in times of future stress.
While idiosyncratic factors might be cited as being responsible for the perception of low liquidity in specific markets, reduced liquidity is unlikely to be a purely conjunctural phenomenon. From a financial stability perspective, some of the structural factors at work can be highlighted, focusing on developments bearing on liquidity conditions at three different levels, namely:
(i) Firms: developments at the level of the main financial firms participating in the core financial markets; (ii) Markets: developments in the structure and functioning of markets themselves; and (iii) System: developments across the global financial system as a whole.
Such structural developments may have served to reinforce the links between liquidity and credit risks, but also the distinction between normal times and times of stress. Many market participants have felt that liquidity pre-LTCM in many markets was underpriced, and that this led financial institutions to underestimate liquidity risks ("liquidity illusion"). Such underpricing inhibited developments that would enhance the market's ability to retain liquidity in times of stress. There have indeed been several occasions since the LTCM crisis when conditions in some markets turned adverse but liquidity, which typically declined sharply in the midst of the crisis, proved to be rather resilient.
However, some elements of recent developments, such as financial consolidation, the increasing use of non-government securities as hedging and valuation benchmarks, might influence the behavior of market participants in a way suggesting that market dynamics in times of extreme stress may have changed significantly. This has heightened concerns about credit risk, which can undermine market participants' willingness to enter into transactions and thus weaken market liquidity in a more uncertain environment. Other elements, such as collateralisation practices and developments in risk management policies, which should generally enhance market stability, could add pressure in times of extreme stress.
Price is a function of liquidity which can be quite detached from normal value. Liquidity offer a new paradigm as the key to understanding why and how the markets move. Liquidity is consistently a reliable indicator on which to base the timing of trading and investment decisions.
Liquidity is the key determinant of the direction of the stock market. The aggregate capitalization of any market or market sector, whether stocks, real estate, precious metals, etc., is a function primarily of liquidity, with the economic value having only secondary impacts. The total value of any market is impacted by the current liquidity trend.
Liquidity is the relationship between changes in the total trading float of shares in the entire stock market and the change in cash available for investment. Stock market liquidity has two components: the change in the trading float and the change in the cash available to buy shares. Liquidity analysis, in essence, is measuring change in the trading float of stock and tracking the movement of cash.
Some analysts offer a daily liquidity number (Daily Liquidity Trim Tabs) that is determined by adding US equity fund inflows, 2/3 of newly announced cash takeovers, 1/3 of completed cash takeovers and subtracting new offerings. Their longer term analysis of the underlying trends in liquidity takes in account stock buybacks, insider selling and margin debt. Mutual Fund Trim Tabs survey over eight hundred and fifty equity and bond funds daily. US stock market liquidity looks at flows into equity mutual fund that are not international specific. International equity and bond funds flow are determined separately. Trim Tabs Market Capitalization Index measures the market value for all NYSE, NASDAQ and AMEX stocks. The AMEX is included but not listed. Trim Tabs Market Cap Index does not include ADR's.
Liquidity analysis starts with the overall economy's cash flow. The best way of watching US cash flow is daily and month income tax collections. Higher income tax collections means higher incomes.
The conventional "value" paradigm says that the overall market capitalization is a function of the growth of aggregate cash flow of all stocks, basically, that the stock market discounts future earnings. This has never worked in reality. Market cap (price) is a always function of liquidity.
The conventional value paradigm is unable to explain why the market capitalization of all US stocks grew from $5.3 trillion at the end of 1994 to $17.7 trillion at the end of 1999, generating a geometric increase in price earnings ratios and the like. Liquidity analysis provides a simple answer. Between the end of 1994 and the end of 1997 the trading float of shares shrank, and from early 1998 through the end of 1999 the trading float was unchanged. Over those same five years the amount of money looking to buy that shrinking or stagnant pool of shares kept growing. The result was that market cap kept rising regardless of economic value. The end result was a stock market up over three times in five years. It is a clear evidence of the Quantity Theory of Money at work.
Money flows from buyers to sellers. If the buyers retired the shares purchased and the sellers - mostly portfolio managers - had to replace their holdings in a smaller float, that adds liquidity. If the sellers vend newly printed shares and used the cash for anything other than buying other shares, that reduces liquidity.
Historically, float change (the number of shares outstanding) is the best leading indicator of future market direction. The float shrinks via stock buybacks and cash takeovers of public companies. The float grows through new public offerings of stock where the proceeds go to the company - meaning the money is not reinvested in shares. The float also grows via insider selling of previously unregistered shares, known as #144 sales, and when stock options are exercised and sold. When insiders exercise and then sell an option, the company takes back the exercised price and withholds estimated capital gains taxes. Of the remaining maybe 50% of the sales price, no more than half is reinvested in stocks, or at most 25% of the sales price.
While there is no cash in the stock market, there is cash sitting in the checking accounts of stock market intermediaries. Daily mutual funds flow of equity and bond funds are closely monitored by market participants. Yet the best leading indicators of future stock market performance are the actions of corporate investors. When corporate investors are net buyers of their own and other public company shares, the overall market sooner or later goes up. Similarly, when corporate investors are net sellers, stocks go down. Mutual fund flows, while large in size, are of less value as a leading indicator. Recent studies have shown that flow is a coincident indicator. That means liquidity changes in the same direction as the market does. Knowing which way the flow will be going is often the key to determining short term swings in the direction of the market.
Therefore, if one knows where liquidity is headed, one knows where the market is headed. With regard to this, our liquidity analysis has consistently proven to be a reliable indicator on which to base the timing of trading and investment decisions; the key to understanding why and how the markets move.
Liquidity determines how strongly news will affect stock prices. Positive liquidity can spur the market significantly higher when other indicators are positive and cushion the fall when those indicators are negative. Conversely, negative liquidity can dampen the effect of good news. Liquidity almost always stays in step with the market and visa versa.
For the economy as a whole, the lower the present rate of interest, the larger, ceteris paribus, would be a future rise, the larger the expected capital loss on securities, and the higher, therefore, the preference for liquid cash balances. As an extreme, though unlikely possibility, Keynes envisaged the case in which even the smallest decline in interest rates would produce a sizable switch into cash balances, which would make the demand curve for cash balances virtually horizontal. This limiting case became popular among Keynesians as the liquidity trap. In his two-asset world of cash and government bonds (the latter that proxy a typical government security for which the central bank can influence the rate of interest), Keynes argues that a liquidity trap would arise if market participants believed that interest rates had bottomed out at a "critical" interest rate level, and that rates should subsequently rise, leading to capital losses on bond holdings. The inelasticity of interest rate expectations at a critical rate would imply that the demand for money would become highly or perfectly elastic at this point (implying both a horizontal money-demand function and LM - liquidity preference/money supply - curve). The monetary authority, then, would not be able to reduce interest rates below the critical rate, as any subsequent monetary expansion would lead investors to increase their demand for liquidity and become net sellers of government bonds. Money-demand growth, then, should accelerate when interest rates reach the critical level.
Keynes argued that there were three reasons why people hold money. They hold cash for transactions purposes, which is what the quantity theory had always said. They also hold money for precautionary reasons, so that in an emergency they would have a ready source of funds. Finally, they hold money for speculative purposes. The speculative motive arose from the effects of interest rates on the price of bonds. When interest rates rise, the price of bonds falls. Thus when people think interest rates are unusually low, they would prefer to hold their assets in the form of money. If they invested in bonds and the interest rate rose, they would suffer a loss. Hence the amount of money people would want to hold should be inversely related to the rate of interest. People will want to hold more money (liquidity) when interest rates are low than when they are higher.
Keynes' introduction of the interest rate into the demand for money has survived in modern finance, but not for the reasons he gave. Keynes was thinking in terms of a two-asset world: money (which earned no interest but which was liquid and had no danger of a capital loss), and bonds (which earned interest but which were not as liquid and which could yield a capital loss). If one thinks not in terms of a two-asset world, but in terms of the range of assets which actually exist in the current financial world, there is no reason to hold cash balances for either precautionary or speculative purposes. There are assets which are both very liquid and which earn interest, such as money market accounts and Treasury bills, and these are a better form in which to hold assets for these purposes, not to mention all manners of options in structure finance.
Though Keynes' explanation of why interest rates influence the demand for money is outdated, other explanations are sound. Money held for transactions purposes is much like inventory which businesses hold. Holding inventories either ties up funds on which a business could earn interest, or uses borrowed funds on which it must pay interest. Thus if a firm can sell $100,000 of its inventory, it has $100,000 in cash which it can either invest to earn interest or pay off debt on which it must pay interest. The cost of inventories increases as interest rates rise or as the size of inventories increases.
However, there are also costs to holding inventories which are too low. If inventories are too small, a business may run out of items and lose sales. Further, if inventories are held at low levels, the business will need to reorder often, and there are usually costs to reordering. Thus the business must balance these costs which rise as inventories increase with the other costs which fall as inventories increase. The problem can be solved elegantly using calculus, but you should be able to see intuitively that a rise in interest rates will decrease the optimal size of inventories, and a rise in the cost of reordering will increase the optimal size. Modern management has introduced just-in-time inventory which renders this argument mute.
When people hold cash balances, they may no longer hold their assets in a form that earns no interest, yet interest rates does generally tend to increase with less liquidity. If interest rates rise on non-money assets relative to money, the cost of holding money in terms of interest foregone rises, and one would expect people to try to economize on cash. A business, for example, could shift money from checking accounts into t-bills, or resort to loans instead of selling assets with high future value. It would be worthwhile to make more transactions into and out of interest-bearing assets to take advantage of the higher interest rates. When interest rates are very low, these transactions may not be worthwhile, and the business may be willing to let money lie idle for short periods in checking accounts.
In a nutshell, the argument boils down to the store-of-value function of money. Money becomes a less desirable way to hold wealth when interest rates on other assets rises, and as a result people will hold smaller cash balances. These considerations lead to a revised demand for money function. The demand for money, or the average amount of money people want to hold, depends positively on expected transactions and negatively on the interest rate. The coefficient should be a negative number because with higher interest rates people should want to hold smaller cash balances.
To complete this part of the model, a money-supply equation and an equilibrium condition is needed. A simple money-supply equation is that money stock is determined outside the system by policy. The logical equilibrium condition is that the market for money balances is in equilibrium when money supply equals money demand. When interest rates are very low, people have no special reason to avoid holding idle cash, and will hold considerable amounts. If they hold lots of cash idle, the fixed amount of money cannot support very much spending. Lots of idle cash means that the representative dollar is not being spent very frequently - i.e. low velocity.
On the other hand, if interest rates are very high, holding idle cash is costly, and people will try to keep their cash holdings low. This means that they will spend money rapidly, or that the velocity of money will be high. With higher interest rates the same fixed quantity of money will support more spending than it did when interest rates were low and people were holding idle cash balances.
The LM curve (Liquidity Preference/Money Supply) shows how much spending some fixed amount of money will support. When interest rates are high, money is spent rapidly and supports a lot of spending. When interest rates are low, the money stock supports less spending. A flattened LM curve is a representation of Liquidity Trap.
The addition of interest rates to the quantity theory allows fiscal policy to have effects within the logic of the quantity theory. If, for example, the government reduces taxes, thereby raising its deficit, it must borrow more. This added borrowing increases the demand for loanable funds and the price of these funds, which is the interest rate, should rise. The higher interest rate makes holding idle funds more expensive, and should result in an increased velocity of money.
Examining the way the ISLM (Investment/Saving - Liquidity Preference/Money Supply Equilibrium) model is constructed reveals that a change in fiscal policy alters only equations that are used to build the IS curve, and changes in monetary policy alters only equations used to build the LM curve. An expansionary fiscal policy will shift the IS curve, increasing interest rates and income. An expansionary monetary policy will shift the LM curve, increasing income but decreasing interest rates. The way in which one shifts these curves is exactly the same as how one shifts curves in the model of supply and demand.
To keep the demand for money constant (which means that the velocity of circulation remains constant), the nominal interest rate must remain constant.
Further, the rate of inflation independently affects the demand for money by changing its desirability as a store of wealth. In cases of very serious inflation, such as the German hyperinflation of 1923, people try to spend money as quickly as possible because it is losing its value. As a result, the velocity of money increases. To some extent estimates of how sensitive money demand is to interest rates may be catching this sensitivity of money demand to inflation because rates of inflation and interest rates move together. A liquidity trap tend to develop in a price deflation environment.
IS curve is a function of the real interest rate; LM curve is a function of the nominal interest rate; IS-LM curve must be drawn with the real interest rate (nominal interest rate - expected inflation rate) and LM curve cannot go below the nominal interest rate = 0 (or the real interest rate = - expected inflation rate).
On May 15, 2001, the United States Federal Reserve Board cut Fed Funds rate by half a percentage point. It was the fifth rate cut this year and brought the total amount of monetary easing to 2.5 percentage points to the current 4%. Greenspan's decision to cut rates in half-point stages every month in 2001, despite criticism that such actions were "too little, too late," was constrained by concerns about inflation. With whole sale prices rising at 3.7% annually, Greenspan is facing zero or negative real interest rates. Obvious excess capacity in the the Old and New economies prevents an interet-rates induced capital spending. The amount of nonperforming loans held by U.S. financial institutions is on the rise. As of the end of March, the amount of distressed loans grew roughly 10 percent from the end of last year. There is also a huge telecom loan fiasco unraveling. This trend continues despite interest rate cuts. A credit crunch is developing in which lender are having difficulty finding qualified borrowers at prime rate. Long-term interest rates, which are not easily affected by Fed policies has been rising. The yield on 10-year Treasury bonds, which at one time had fallen to levels around 4.5 percent, have recently risen to around 5.73 percent yesterday (June 13). This reflects the limits of credit easing and the possibility of future inflation. This rise in long-term interest rates, coupled with the macroeconomic slowdown and the decline in corporate earnings, forms the backdrop against which stock prices are falling. This could also lead to a vicious circle in which lower stock prices affect consumer spending.
The U.S., just as Japan, appears to be falling into a liquidity trap.
Henry C.K. Liu
References:
Liquidity
From: Henry C.K. Liu
Prev by Date: Macedonia: Washington's Military-Intelligence Ploy
Next by Date: Re: The Quantity Theory of Money
Previous by thread: Liquidity
Next by thread: query -- monetary policy
Index(es):
Date
Thread
Thread context:
query -- monetary policy, Jim Devine Thu 14 Jun 2001, 21:53 GMT
<Possible follow-up(s)>
Re: query -- monetary policy, Niggle, Christopher Fri 15 Jun 2001, 23:55 GMT
Re: query -- monetary policy, Basil Moore Sun 17 Jun 2001, 18:33 GMT
Liquidity, Henry C.K. Liu Thu 14 Jun 2001, 21:36 GMT
Re: Liquidity, Basil Moore Sun 17 Jun 2001, 18:32 GMT
Fwd: Re: [PEN-L:13277] similarities and differencies between postkeynesian & marxian economics, Jim Devine Thu 14 Jun 2001, 18:23 GMT
David's query, Paul Davidson Thu 14 Jun 2001, 15:53 GMT
<Possible follow-up(s)>
Re: David's query, David Dequech Fri 15 Jun 2001, 20:27 GMT
Re: David's query, Paul Davidson Sun 17 Jun 2001, 15:24 GMT